1. Introduction
In the standard economic literature, national savings and investments played an important role to create a higher level of economic growth and development through the capital formation and accumulation process. For example, Keynes’ general theory of employment, interest rates, and money and Capitalist Economics (1933–1970) both demonstrated the importance of liquidity in economic expansion. The injection of capital into the economy was considered as the key resource to increase investment and output production (Asimakopulos, 1983). The same could be said of International Macroeconomics, which believed that finance and trade deregulation could boost domestic and global economic growth through foreign direct and portfolio investment (Mohamed Mustafa, 2019; Tung & Thang, 2020). Therefore, domestic capital accumulation and capital mobility became the main source of economic expansion.
Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000) raised the issue of six major puzzles to challenge the international macroeconomic phenomena. They questioned the six puzzles that were unanswered in some industrial countries. For example, the home bias puzzle in trading between the individual in the same country and foreigners, the pricing puzzles, the exchange rate disconnect puzzle, home bias in equity portfolios, and consumption correlation. Besides the puzzles in trading, Obstfeld and Rogoff also pointed out the puzzle in international capital mobility, called by the name of two scholars Feldstein-Horioka (F-H). The F-H is a puzzle because they assumed the dependent relationship between national savings and investments that contradicts the standard international macroeconomic. Hence, we should expect perfect capital mobility as a result of trade and investment liberalization, in which individual investment and savings are allowed to be invested in any country with a higher marginal product of investment until the returns of the two countries are equal. When interest rates are arbitrarily set, savers in the United States would invest in foreign countries to get a larger return. This suggested, theoretically, that national investments and savings should have been correlated at a low level, or independent, depending on the extent of financial liberalization and arbitrary interest rate (Obstfeld & Rogoff, 2000).
However, empirically, evidence shows the existence of the contradiction between standard international macroeconomics and real-world situation. There are numerous empirical proofs that the relationship between economic variables may not follow standard economic theory. This phenomenon was widely known as a “puzzle”. Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000) found that there are still “many puzzles” existing in economic literature, particularly in international macroeconomics and finance. For instance, the studies of Feldstein and Horioka (1980) initially found a strong correlation between domestic investment and saving (S-I) in some industrial countries. This puzzle is become well known as the Feldstein- Horioka puzzle. They reasoned that if the saving and investment (S-I) assumption is correct and capital mobility is perfect, we should examine the correlation between domestic investment and savings. The results from their study found a strong correlation between saving and investment in some developed countries during 1960–74. (i.e., Australia, UK, Germany).
Feldstein and Horioka (1980) described five rationales behind this correlation of S-I. First, it is because the domestic tax regime discourages investors to invest abroad. This tax regime discounts the return of investment and makes national savings and investment significantly correlated. If the investors invest their savings in other countries, there will be no correlation between S-I. Second, the cost of the transaction, fees, custody, or dealing costs in different countries are volatile. This discourages investors to invest outside and instead invest in their home country, where these costs are calculable and lower. As a result, domestic savings are retained within the country, and we end up with an S-I correlation. Third, there are some exchange rate risks when investing in foreign countries, particularly when withdrawing money back to one’s home country. This fluctuation in the exchange rate deters risk-averse investors from investing abroad. Following that, information asymmetry issues may occur outside of the country, causing domestic investors to incur additional costs of information seeking and forcing them to invest only within the country. Finally, foreign investment may be subject to unanticipated regulatory risks imposed by a foreign government. Five reasons as mentioned provide insights behind the international flow of capital during the 1980s (Byrne et al., 2009).
The interpretation of Feldstein and Horioka (1980) inspired the later scholars to study the nexus between saving and investment (S-I) and made the Feldstein and Horioka puzzle receive more interest later on. This puzzle has been widely tested by a number of studies. They found that capital immobility happened due to the country’s capital constraints and some restrictions imposed on the outward investment promotion.
Unfortunately, most studies were aimed at advancing economies and industrial countries. Only a small number of studies explained this puzzle in less developing countries like Asia, Africa, and developing Latin American (Narayan, 2005). Nevertheless, from 2005 to 2010, there were some empirical studies (Jiranyakul & Brahmasrene, 2008; Narayan, 2005) that tested the validity of such a theoretical puzzle in less developing countries but not in two fast-growing economies like Thailand and China. Thailand as the home country for Tom-Yum-Kung or the Asian financial crisis in 1997, which changed their exchange rate regime from pegged to a managed float system, needs to be tested whether their financial market has fully operated globally. China on the other hand, as one of the powerful investor of the world, mainly after the exchange-rate regime switching in 1998 and WTO participation in 2001, also need to be studied. Because, if the massive investment and saving in China outflow to other countries, this magnificent amount will structurally change the landscape of investment of the whole region, particularly, countries along the one-belt- one-road routes where their S-I shared a certain level of correlation with China.
This study, therefore, aimed to provide additional empirical evidence to test the existence of the F-H puzzle in Thailand and China during the period of structural change. Most studies employed the classical model (Granger cointegration), only a few studies employed the modern method. The methodology of this study therefore employed modern time-series econometrics which is ARDL Bounds Testing from the study of Narayan (2005). This approach is considered as a better way to test the cointegration between the two non-stationary variables (Pesaran et al., 2001), particularly data with different levels of integration. The main contributions of this paper would consist of 1) provision of additional empirical evidence on major puzzles in international macroeconomics literature in Asia, and 2) empirical evidence supporting the approach of ARDL Bounds Testing.
2. Data and Methodology
The aim of this study was to test the existence of the F-H puzzle by looking at capital mobility. This objective, in particular, can be achieved by testing the cointegration between national savings and investments (S-I). If a strong correlation exists, it implies that the F-H puzzle exists. That is the national savings and investments share a certain level of correlation if investors in that country are not inclined to invest abroad, or there may have been regulations in place to prevent money outflow. If the S-I correlation is independent, the F-H puzzle does not exist. The S-I can then be invested independently in any country with higher returns. For the data time point, this study collected yearly national savings and investments as a fraction of GDP during 1980–2019. The methodology follows four stages of ARDL-Bound Testing for integration. In the first stage, the unit root test for the order of integration was undertaken. The main point was to diagnose the basic assumption of stationary and to ensure the absence of structural break problem. The second stage was about the ARDL-Bound testing for integration of Thailand and China. In the case of Thailand, the purpose of this study was to extend the empirical findings of Jirayakul and Brahmasrene (2008) and to accomplish a longer period of research from 1990 to 2006 and from 1980–2019, which included the 1997 financial crisis.
As shown in Figure 1, the data depicted the movement of national savings and investments during the previous study in 1990–2006 and the extension 1980–2019. This study covered three significant periods, namely, pre-crisis, tipping point (structural break of investment during the financial crisis in 1997), and post-crisis.
Figure 1: Saving and Investment as a Percentage of Real GDP in Thailand (1980–2019)
While in the case of China, this study extended data coverage of Narayan (2005) from 1952–1998 and 1980–2019. The main finding will provide more evidence to the previous studies and to support the existence of the F-H puzzle in China after passing through two magnificent structural changes, which are the exchange rate regime-switching and the WTO participation. Figure 2 depicted the movement of savings and investments (S-I) as a fraction of real GDP in China during 2 significant periods: 1952–1994 and 1994–2019.
Figure 2: Saving and Investment as a Percentage of Real GDP in China (1980–2019)
In the third stage, this study aimed to achieve the Error Correction Model (ECM) if cointegration was found. The ECM would help to investigate a short-run equilibrium adjustment in their long-run model. In the final stage, the cumulative sum (CUSUM) and cumulative sum square (CUSUMSQ) are adopted to satisfy the structural break assumption.
Annual national savings and investments in Thailand were retrieved from the National Economic and Social Development Council (NESDC). The authors then calculated the savings and the private investments as the fraction of the real GDP of Thailand following Jiranyakul and Brahmasrene (2008). The authors, however, extended the time period starting from 1980 to 2019 or 39 time periods. In the case of China, the model was formulated using the annual data from 1994–2018, which was retrieved from the China National Bureau of Statistics (NBS). The authors extended the empirical finding from Narayan (2005) whose study was based on the period of fixed exchange rate regime (1952–1994 and 1952–1998), to see if there was a structural change relative to 1952–1994 or after the China WTO 2001 participation. The data for both countries is presented in Table 1.
Table 1: Selected Annual Investment and Savings as Percent of GDP (1980–2019)
Source: Authors calculated from Thailand NESDC and China NBS.
3. Model Construction
Under the modern econometric era, multiples tools for long-run correlation were available and widely applied in various fields of literature (Pesaran et al., 2001; Engle & Granger, 1987). To set up the empirical model, this study followed previous studies (Obstfeld & Rogoff, 2000; Pesaran et al., 2001; Jiranyakul & Brahmasrene, 2008), which was explained by the following stages. First, we indicated the nexus between S-I in regard to Feldstein-Horioka regression, the relation of S-I is expressed as
\(\left(\frac{I}{Y}\right)_{r}=a_{0}+a_{1}\left(\frac{\mathrm{NS}}{Y}\right)_{t}+\varepsilon_{t}\) (1)
Engle and Granger (1987) strictly required that all variables must be integrated of order one or I(1) and must be known before performing the cointegration test. This study thus assumed a null hypothesis that national private investment (I) would be contingent on domestic saving (S) if savings and investment were integrated of the similar order I(1). Therefore, to trace the long-run relationship, we first tested the order of integration under the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) and then estimated the ordinary least square (OLS) of two variables in equation (1) where Y represents the real GDP, I represent the investments, and NS represents the national savings.
However, if the same integrated order of stationary by Engle and Granger failed to achieve, we should proceed to a more relaxed approach. Pesaran et al. (2001) then proposed a new method that required a more relaxed assumption of the integration. This approach was called ARDL bounds testing procedure. This approach is mainly based on conditional autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) and error correction mechanism (ECM). The ARDL cointegration technique is used in determining the long-run relationship between series with different order of integration (Narayan, 2005; Jiranyakul & Brahmasrene, 2008; Saleem & Sial, 2015). That is, ARDL could examine cointegration relationships amongst variables regardless of their order of integration, I(0), I(1), or a mixture of both.
In the second stage, we indicated the model specification based on the ARDL instead of Engle and Granger (1987). The model was specified as:
\(\begin{aligned} \Delta\left(\frac{I}{Y}\right)_{t}= \alpha_{0}+\sum_{i=1}^{p} \beta_{t} \Delta\left(\frac{I}{Y}\right)_{t-1}+\sum_{i=1}^{q} \gamma_{t} \Delta\left(\frac{\mathrm{NS}}{Y}\right)_{t-j}+\lambda \Delta\left(\frac{\mathrm{NS}}{Y}\right)_{t}+\varepsilon_{t} \end{aligned}\) (2)
Where the expression (3) and (4) provided an autoregressive part (lag of endogenous variables) and the distributed lag (lags of exogenous variables) by adding the lagged level variables into equation (2). The α, β, γ are the parameters of short-run variables and λ was the parameter of the long-run variables. The study then obtained the F-statistic by estimating equations (3) and (4) for both countries as following equations;
Thailand:
\(\begin{aligned} \Delta(I / Y)_{-} \mathrm{TH}_{t}=& \alpha_{01}+\alpha_{11}(I / Y)_{-} \mathrm{TH}_{t-1} \\ &+\alpha_{12}(\mathrm{NS} / Y)_{-} \mathrm{TH}_{t-1} \\ &+\sum_{i=1}^{P} \beta_{t} \Delta(I / Y)_{-} \mathrm{TH}_{t-i} \\ &+\sum_{i=1}^{\varphi} \gamma_{j} \Delta(\mathrm{NS} / Y)_{-} \mathrm{TH}_{\mathrm{s}-j} \\ &+\lambda \Delta(\mathrm{NS} / Y)_{-} \mathrm{TH}_{t}+\varepsilon_{s} \end{aligned}\) (3)
China:
\(\begin{aligned} \Delta(I / Y)_{-} \mathrm{CN}_{t}=& \alpha_{02}+\alpha_{21}(I / Y)_{-} \mathrm{CN}_{t-1} \\ &+\alpha_{22}(\mathrm{NS} / Y)_{-} \mathrm{CN}_{r-1} \\ &+\sum_{i=1}^{p} \beta_{r} \Delta(I / Y)_{-} \mathrm{CN}_{t-j} \\ &+\sum_{i=1}^{q} \gamma_{j} \Delta(\mathrm{NS} / Y)_{-} \mathrm{CN}_{r-j} \\ &+\lambda \Delta(\mathrm{NS} / Y)_{-} \mathrm{CN}_{t}+\varepsilon_{t} \end{aligned}\) (4)
Next, we compared the computation of F-statistics from (3) and (4) with the critical bound values obtained from the Narayan (2005) (Case 3: (unrestricted intercepts; no to Pesaran trends) a0 ≠ 0 and a1 = 0. According to Pesaran et al. (2001), there are 5 cases provided for testing the cointegrating bound test). This was because it fit better with a small number of observations (Jiranyakul & Brahmasrene, 2008). The hypotheses for integration were presented in Table 2.
Table 2: Hypotheses for Thailand and China
In addition to the ARDL, if cointegration exists, this study could further find the short-run equilibrium adjustment obtained from the error correction model (ECM) by replacing the lagged level variables in equations (3) and (4) with the one-period lagged residuals from the estimate of equation (1).
4. Results
In the first stage, we tested the unit root under the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP). The results, as shown in Table 3, concluded that S-I as a fraction of real GDP was non-stationary in level with trend and without trend in Thailand. However, both variables were stationary after the first difference or I(1). While in the case of China, the saving ratio was stationary at the level I(0) in all cases. The investment ratio was nonstationary until we took the first difference.
Table 3: Tests for Unit Root
Note: a) The number in [square brackets] is the optimal lag length determined by Schwartz information criterion (SIC) with a maximum lag of 9. b) The number in {curly brackets} is the optimal bandwidth determined by the Newly-West using Bartlett Kernel. c) The number in (parentheses) is the p-value provided by MacKinnon (1996). d) *, **, and *** denotes 10, 5, and 1 percent significance levels, respectively.
5. ARDL-ECM Cointegration Study
The bounds testing procedure simply estimates OLS regression with the first difference of the variables in equation (2). Then, put the lagged level variables and conduct the additional test. Finally, compute the F-statistics and compare them with the critical values (Narayan 2005) (Case 3: (unrestricted intercepts; no trends)). The result displayed in Table 4 showed the ARDL equation for Thailand and China with the computed F-statistics and χ2. The estimated result shows the computed F-statistics for Thailand and China was 2.753 and 9.147 respectively. In addition, the LM test was applied to diagnose the serial correlation. The result indicated no serial correlation problem since the p-value of χ2(2) was greater than 0.05 for both Thailand and China.
Now, to conclude the cointegration, we compared the computed F-statistics shown in Table 4 with the Bounds critical value in Table 5. In Thailand’s case, the study concluded that the F-statistics was below the lower bound for both studies (Pesaran et al., 2001; Narayan, 2005). Thus, the cointegration between national savings and investment did not exist. The result of Thailand matched with Jiranyakul and Brahmasrene (2008). Whereas, China exhibited a strong and significant cointegration between national savings and investments. The computed F-statistic was 9.147, which was located above the upper bound for both studies (Pesaran et al., 2001; Narayan, 2005). Our result was similar to Narayan (2005) that cointegration existed after the fixed exchange rate regime (1994–2019).
Table 4: Results of ARDL Test for Cointegration
Note: a. The number in parenthesis is t-statistics. b. *, **, and *** denotes 10, 5, and 1 percent significance levels, respectively. c. LM χ2(2) is statistics for testing no residual serial correlation against orders 2.
Table 5: The Bounds Critical Value
Note: Critical value obtained from the study of Pesaran, Shin, and Smith (2001) and Narayan (2005), case III Unrestricted intercept and no trend (fit better with 30–80 observations).
6. The Long Run Estimation Results (Case of China)
Since the cointegration of S-I existed in China, the authors further constructed the long-run model using the estimated equation (5) to ensure the robustness of the model. The estimated long-run coefficients, as well as the robustness test which included the serial correlation, normality, and heteroscedasticity tests, were presented in Table 6.
Table 6: Estimated Long Run Coefficients (ARDL, 1, 1)
Note: *, **, and ***denotes 10, 5, and 1 percent significance level, respectively.
\(\frac{I}{Y}=\alpha_{0}+\sum_{i-0}^{m} \alpha_{1}\left(\frac{I}{Y}\right)_{t-j}+\sum_{i=0}^{n} \alpha_{2}\left(\frac{N S}{Y}\right)_{r-1}+\mu_{t}\) (5)
Results in Table 6 suggested that the long-run model was robust as it presented no serial correlation and heteroscedasticity problem. The model also indicated strong and significant long-run relationships between S-I during 1994–2019. We concluded the existence of the F-H puzzle in China during a particular period as we significantly found cointegration of S-I evidenced from both ARDL Bound testing and the long-run model.
7. The Estimated Error Correction Model (Case of China)
Table 7 presented the short-run dynamic results between national savings and investments along with the diagnostic test. The error correction (ECt−1) was selected based on adjusted R-square corresponding diagnostic statistics. The error correction ECt−1 represented the speed of adjustment or equilibrium reversion in the dynamic model after any disequilibrium (Pesaran et al., 2001). The ECM suggested that the result was negative and statistically significant with a 95% confidence level, which was similar to the findings of Narayan (2005). This meant that the result confirmed the existence of a long-run relationship of S-I and strong equilibrium reversion in China.
Table 7: Error Correction Model (ECM), Dependent Variable ∆I_CNt
Note: a. Cointegration equation EC = IGDP_CN - (0.8573*SGDP_CN). b. *, **, and *** denotes 10, 5, and 1 percent significance level, respectively.
8. Stability Test
In addition to the unit root test, the study plotted the cumulative sum (CUSUM) and cumulative sum square (CUSUMSQ) to ensure the model passed the necessary assumptions of stationary and the structural break. The stability test such as the cumulative sum (CUSUM) and cumulative sum square (CUSUMSQ) tests was used to investigate the stability of the equation (2). There appear to be no structural breaks in the two countries. The results were depicted in Figures 3 and 4.
Figure 3: Stability Test for Thailand (TH)
Figure 4: Stability Test for China (CN)
9. Conclusion
This study aimed to provide more empirical results to international macroeconomic and finance literature by investigating the F-H hypothesis. We carefully tested the existence of cointegration between national savings and investments (S-I) in Thailand and China by ARDL-Bounds testing procedure. Annual national savings and investments data was retrieved from the National Economic and Social Development Board (NESDB) of Thailand during 1980–2019 and the National Bureau of Statistics of China during 1994–2019. The time-series data diagnosis passed all basic assumptions of stationary claimed by the ADF and PP unit root test. The results from CUSUM also suggested that there was no structural break found over the whole period of study (1980–2019). To conclude the cointegration results, this study borrowed the Bound Critical Value from Narayan (2005), which was suitable for a smaller number of observations compared to Pesaran et al. (2001). As a result of the computed F-statistic (2.753) not satisfying the necessary bound value, this study showed no long-run association between S-I in Thailand. The cointegration results of Thailand supported the empirical results from Jirayakul and Brahmasrene (2008) and Byrne and Fiess (2009). This is due to the difference in the level of financial market development and economic growth (Tariq et al., 2020) and interest rate arbitrage in Asian countries which causes capital movement in Asian countries. Whereas, this study found a strong correlation in the case of China during the fixed exchange rate regime switching in 1994 and post WTO participation in 2001. The computed F-statistic (9.147) strongly indicated the long-run relationship. This capital immobility happens due to the country’s capital constraints and some restrictions imposed on the outward investment promotion, as well as the home bias in investment among Chinese investors. In addition, the long-run equation and the Error Correction Model (ECM) were estimated to ensure the existence of a long-run relationship and short-run equilibrium adjustment respectively. We strongly found evidence of a long-run relationship of S-I which implied that the F-H puzzle exists in China. In the same word, we found strong nexus and capital immobility after China’s exchange rate regime-switching and WTO participation. Our results were in line and provide an extended finding of Narayan (2005) that a long-run relationship of S-I was found during 1994–2019 regardless of the structural break during exchange rate regime switching in 1998 and post-WTO participation in 2001.
참고문헌
- Asimakopulos, A. (1983). Kalecki and Keynes on finance, investment, and saving. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 7(3/4), 221-233. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/7.3-4.221
- Byrne, J., Fazio, G., & Fiess, N. (2009). The global side of the investment-saving puzzle. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 41(5), 1033-1040. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2009.00244
- Engle, F., & Granger, J. (1987). Co-integration and error correction: Representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251-276. https://doi.org/10.2307/1913236
- Feldstein, M., & Horioka, C. (1980). Domestic saving and international capital flows. The Economic Journal, 90(358), 314-329. https://doi.org/10.2307/2231790
- Jiranyakul, K., & Brahmasrene, T. (2008). Cointegration between investment and saving in selected Asian countries: ARDL bounds testing procedure cointegration between investment and saving in selected Asian countries, Munich Personal RePEc Archive, 11, 45-76. https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/45076/
- Mohamed Mustafa, A. M. (2019). Contribution of tourism and foreign direct investment to a gross domestic product: Econometric analysis in the case of Sri Lanka. The Journal of Asian Finance, Economics, and Business, 6(4), 109-114. https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2019.vol6. no4.109
- Narayan, K. (2005). The saving and investment nexus for China: Evidence from cointegration tests. Applied Economics, 37(17), 1979-1990. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036840500278103
- Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (2000). The six major puzzles in international macroeconomics: Is there a common cause? Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
- Pesaran, H., Shin, Y., & Smith, J. (2001). Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16(3), 289-326 https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.616
- Saleem, A., & Sial, M. (2015). Exports-growth nexus in Pakistan: Cointegration and causality analysis. Pakistan Economic and Social Review, 53(1), 17-30. https://www.jstor.org/stable/26153247
- Tariq, R., Khan, M. A., & Rahman, A. (2020). How does financial development impact economic growth in Pakistan?: New evidence from threshold model. The Journal of Asian Finance, Economics, and Business, 7(8), 161-173. https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2020.vol7.no8.161
- Tung, L. T., & Thang, P. N. (2020). Impact of FDI on private investment in the Asian and African developing countries: A panel data approach. The Journal of Asian Finance, Economics, and Business, 7(3), 295-302. https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2020.vol7.no3.295
피인용 문헌
- The Effect of Financial Liberalization on Economic Growth: The Case of Egypt and Saudi Arabia vol.8, pp.11, 2021, https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2021.vol8.no11.0203
- The Asymmetric Effect of Oil Price Shocks on Economic Growth and Real Exchange Rate in Saudi Arabia vol.8, pp.12, 2021, https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2021.vol8.no12.0295