DOI QR코드

DOI QR Code

Behavioral Biases on Investment Decision: A Case Study in Indonesia

  • KARTINI, Kartini (Department of Management, Faculty of Business and Economics, Universitas Islam Indonesia) ;
  • NAHDA, Katiya (Department of Management, Faculty of Business and Economics, Universitas Islam Indonesia)
  • 투고 : 2020.11.30
  • 심사 : 2021.02.16
  • 발행 : 2021.03.30

초록

A shift in perspective from standard finance to behavioral finance has taken place in the past two decades that explains how cognition and emotions are associated with financial decision making. This study aims to investigate the influence of various psychological factors on investment decision-making. The psychological factors that are investigated are differentiated into two aspects, cognitive and emotional aspects. From the cognitive aspect, we examine the influence of anchoring, representativeness, loss aversion, overconfidence, and optimism biases on investor decisions. Meanwhile, from the emotional aspect, the influence of herding behavior on investment decisions is analyzed. A quantitative approach is used based on a survey method and a snowball sampling that result in 165 questionnaires from individual investors in Yogyakarta. Further, we use the One-Sample t-test in testing all hypotheses. The research findings show that all of the variables, anchoring bias, representativeness bias, loss aversion bias, overconfidence bias, optimism bias, and herding behavior have a significant effect on investment decisions. This result emphasizes the influence of behavioral factors on investor's decisions. It contributes to the existing literature in understanding the dynamics of investor's behaviors and enhance the ability of investors in making more informed decision by reducing all potential biases.

키워드

1. Introduction

Optimal portfolio investment as explained by Markowitz (1952) is focused on two things, (1) how to maximize investment returns at a given level of risk, or (2) minimizing risks at a certain level of return. In building a portfolio theory, Markowitz (1952) assumed that all investors are rational individuals in making a decision. Therefore, all the decisions made are expected to generate the highest utility possible through a variety of rational analysis processes. Not only modern portfolio theory but also a range of other conventional finance theories, such as capital asset pricing model (CAPM) (Treynor, 1961; Sharpe, 1964; Lintner, 1965; Mossin, 1969) and efficient market hypothesis (EMH) (Fama, 1970) use the same assumptions, that investors are always rational.

Barberis and Thaler (2003) explained that rational behavior should cover two things. First, when investors receive new information, they will update their beliefs appropriately and accurately. Second, based on the new beliefs, the investors will make the right decisions consistent with the explanation of conventional finance theories. Hence, biases will not occur in an investment decision, as each individual is considered to have the capability of selecting the best alternatives among various options that are available, based on complete calculations, theories, concepts, and the right approaches.

A basic question put forward by a few theorists of behavioral finance, is “are investors always rational?” (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979; De Bondt & Thaler, 1985; Shefrin & Statman, 1985; Shiller, 1987). According to them, the assumption of investor rationality is not easily fulfilled, since investors make decisions when presented with alternatives that involve risk, probability, and uncertainty. People choose between different options (or prospects) and how they estimate (many times in a biased or incorrect way) the perceived likelihood of each of these options. They also state that financial decision-makers not only involve logical and rational considerations, but also psychological aspects that are at times irrational, involving intuition. Hence, it may deviate from the rationality assumption.

Behavioral Economics is the study of psychology as it relates to the economic decision-making processes of individuals and institutions. Behavioral economics reveals systematic deviations from rationality exposed by investors. Individuals are victims of their cognitive biases that lead to the existence of financial market inefficiencies and anomalies (Al-Mansour, 2020). Literally, decision-making is a process of selecting the best alternative from a number of possible options available in complex situations (Hirschey & Nofsinger, 2008). The complexity of it then makes the investor simplify decision-making in drawing the right conclusions (Shefrin, 2007). Therefore, the information acquired and the level of investor ability to process the information is highly affected by the quality of the decisions made. Further, Shefrin (2007) stated that a range of behavioral bias practices or irrational behavior is mainly caused by investor’s limited ability to analyze information and the emotional factor in decision making.

The concept of behavioral finance has arisen from the assumption that human beings as social as well as intellectual creatures involve mind and emotion in decision making. According to Hirschey and Nofsinger (2008), behavioral finance is defined as “A study of cognitive errors and emotions in financial decisions”. They explained that the concept of behavioral finance is a study of financial decision-making caused by emotional and cognitive factors. Pompian (2006) divided decision-making biases into two categories – cognitive and emotional biases. The former is a bias that is associated with the thought process, while the latter is associated with feelings and emotions. Asri (2013) classified cognitive bias into 3 groups as suggested by Shefrin (2000):

a. The bias of simplifying decision-making processes by using rules of thumb is known as heuristic bias. Heuristics are commonly defined as cognitive shortcuts or rules of thumb that simplify decisions, especially under conditions of uncertainty. This group comprises availability, hindsight, and representativeness biases.

b. The bias of reaction to information based on the information’s frameworks is called a framing effect. The framing effect is a cognitive bias where people decide on options based on whether the options are presented with positive or negative connotations; as a loss or as a gain. Framing bias occurs when people make a decision based on the way the information is presented, as opposed to just on the facts themselves. The same facts presented in two different ways can lead to people making different judgments or decisions. Framing is as important as a substance that was previously ignored by traditional finance. This group consists of overreaction, conservatism, anchoring, and confirmation biases.

c. The bias of understanding information and self-adjusting to the market price is known as prior bias. The prior bias, heuristic bias, and framing effect, will at last cause prices to deviate from their fundamental value, thus the market will be inefficient. This group includes optimism, overconfidence, and mental accounting biases.

Sha and Ismail (2020) explained that investors make decisions based on the available information, and the issue is related to how they build their perception of that information. In this context, the investors should be aware of the different types of cognitive biases that may lead them to a much better or worst position. They found that the investors are influenced by different cognitive biases and it depends on the gender of the investor.

Based on previous research findings and phenomena, this research makes a further investigation about the influence of biases, both cognitive and emotional, on investment decision making. Shefrin (2002) described that behavioral finance is not a science to defeat the market. The most important part of this concept is the recognition of the existing risk from an investor sentiment or the risk that arises due to psychological factors that are sometimes larger than the fundamental risk.

This study was corroborated by Kartini and Nuris (2015) who stated that the various biases that occur can be detrimental, as it can lead to a risk miscalculation that may occur. Besides, such biases are also difficult to control because they are invisible and directly linked to thought processes involving emotions or feelings. Despite the controlling difficulty, Olsen (1998) warned that the main purpose of behavioral finance is understanding the influence of psychological factors systematically in the financial market so that each individual will be more prudent in decision making.

This research attempts to investigate the influence of various psychological factors on investment decision-making. The psychological factors to be investigated are differentiated into two aspects as explained by Pompian (2006), cognitive and emotional aspects. Accordingly, this study examines the influence of anchoring, representativeness, loss aversion, overconfidence, and optimism biases on investor decisions. Meanwhile, the latter aspect to be examined is the influence of herding behavior on investment decisions.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Investment Decision

Investment decisions are the process of choosing investment from various alternatives that are commonly affected by the past investment’s returns and the expected returns in the future (Subash, 2012). There are two kinds of investors in making investment decisions, rational investor and irrational investor. Rational investors are those who make a decision merely based on logical thinking and information about the investment prospect. While irrational investors decide based on their psychological aspect which creates biases in investment decisions.

2.2. Prospect Theory

Prospect theory is proposed by Kahneman and Tversky (1979). In general, it explains how investors make decisions under certain risks. According to them, individuals assess their loss and gain perspectives asymmetrically. Thus, contrary to the expected utility theory (which models the decision that perfectly rational agents would make), prospect theory aims to describe the actual behavior of people. They found that losses hurt about twice as much as gains make us feel good. That is people feel the pain of loss twice as strongly as they feel pleasure at an equal gain. The thought that the pain of losing is psychologically about twice as powerful as the pleasure of gaining is known as loss aversion. The other implication of prospect theory is people tend to take larger risks to avoid losses, rather than take risks to earn profits. To put it another way, investors will be inclined to be risk-averse, when coming across profits and switch to be risk-takers when perceiving losses. This finding contrasts with the expected utility theory from Markowitz (1952) who stated that a rational investor will exhibit consistent behavior, whether he/she is a risk-averse or a risk-taker under any circumstances.

2.3. Heuristic Theory

The term heuristic was introduced by Tversky and Kahneman (1974) who described that the decisions made amid complexities and conditions of uncertainty are mostly based on the beliefs concerning the likelihood of uncertain events. Uncertainty in events is uncertainty regarding either the occurrence of an event. These beliefs then form a heuristic way of thinking, by which people tend to use rules of thumb to simplify the decision-making processes. This view was strengthened by De Bondt et al. (2008) that individuals (investors) have a bias in their belief that will affect how they think and make decisions. Fromlet (2001) defined heuristics as “the use of experience and practical efforts” that is an effort to interpret information quickly by relying on experiences accompanied by intuition. It explains how individuals or groups make decisions under conditions of uncertainty. Investors frequently make mistakes in decision making because they use rules of thumb as a basis in processing the information. On the one hand, a heuristic approach can facilitate faster decision making. This approach may result in biases or errors that occur systematically. Tversky and Kahneman (1974) classified heuristic bias into 3 types - representativeness, availability, and anchoring biases that will be investigated in this study.

2.4. Framing Theory

The subsequent discussion of cognitive bias after heuristics dealing is framing. According to Frensidy (2016), traditional finance assumes that framing is transparent. Meanwhile, behaviorists think of it differently, many frames are not so transparent that investors have difficulty seeing it clearly. Consequently, the decisions made will be highly dependent on how the information is framed or presented. Based on the previous experiment, Frensidy (2016) described someone (suppose called Budi), in a different way by using the same information on two separate groups, group A and B. In group A, Budi is said to be a smart, diligent, impulsive, critical, stubborn, and jealous person, whereas, in group B, Budi is described as a jealous, stubborn, critical, impulsive, diligent, and smart person. The same characteristics about Budi but presented in reverse order turn out to significantly influence the groups’ assessment results. The experiment results reveal that the characteristics mentioned earlier have more influence than those mentioned later. Group A significantly asses Budi better than group B do. He argued that there are two reasons which explain such phenomena. First, one’s concentration level may decrease with the increasing amount of information to be absorbed, so that the information placed behind gets less attention. Second, first impressions usually receive more weight than the information that comes after. These two things then lead to anchoring bias to occur.

3. Hypotheses Development

3.1. Anchoring Bias and Investment Decisions

According to Tversky and Kahneman (1974), anchoring bias occurs when people rely too much on pre-existing information or the first information they find when making decisions (anchor). Then, adjustment is made on such perception. Investors who are affected by this bias tend to underlie their investment decisions on one certain information, regardless of whether the information is first acquired, or it is the only information available which made people highly rely on it. Ackert and Deaves (2009) defined overconfidence as the tendency of a person to overestimate knowledge, ability, and the accuracy of the information that an investor possesses, or the tendency to become too optimistic about the future and ability. Such an investor must be wary of anchoring bias. Despite the different information available, people tend to be inclined to the first-owned information in making a decision.

Many investors in the capital market experience anchoring bias that most of them continue to remember the buying price of shares in their portfolio. The selling decision is frequently based on the buying price as the reference point. Investors decide to sell their shares sooner when the price is above the reference point. Besides buying price, the highest price of shares that has ever been achieved during a certain period also frequently become reference price. Yet, many investors are not willing to cut loss cause they refer to such reference prices (Frensidy, 2016). Thus, a hypothesis is proposed as follows:

H1: Anchoring bias will affect investment decisions.

3.2. Representativeness Bias and Investment Decisions

Representativeness bias is someone’s tendency to make decisions based on certain stereotypes or prior knowledge or experiences. Representativeness bias happens when people make decisions only by limited observations to acquire information from the surrounding environment and ignore other information (Baker & Nofsinger, 2002; Ritter, 2003; Shefrin, 2000). Representativeness bias tends to lead investors to overreact during processing information in making decisions (Kahneman & Riepe, 1998). It is supported by the findings of Franses (2007) and Marsden et al. (2008) who revealed that the representativeness bias can cause over-reaction behavior to occur as reflected in the stock prices. On the other hand, investors who are affected by this bias can also ignore or not pay close attention to important events that may happen in the future. Hence, they do not protect themselves from such unexpected events (Yoong, 2010).

Representativeness bias can lead someone to make a wrong conclusion. Higher-priced products are often decided with higher quality than lower-priced ones, although there is a likelihood that prices do not always reflect quality. Chen et al. (2007) explained that the common stereotypes in the capital market are investors tend to interpret the good characteristics of a company, such as product quality, reliable managers, and high growth as the characteristics of the company that has a worthwhile investment.

The other error of representativeness bias that often occurs in the financial market as described by Frensidy (2016) is the assumption that past performance is the best indicator to predict future performance. In other words, investors often believe that past rates of return represent future expected return. If a company announces successive profit increases, investors will assume that it will continue to rise and consider this company a good company, which means good investment. Therefore, investors expect higher returns for past winners’ stocks and use this trend as a stereotype for future stock movements (Lakonishok et al., 1994; Ackert & Deaves, 2010). Thus, based on the explanations and reviews on earlier studies, a hypothesis is proposed as follows:

H2: Representativeness bias will affect investment decisions.

3.3. Loss Aversion and Investment Decisions

According to Pompian (2006), loss aversion is the tendency to prefer avoiding losses to acquiring equivalent gains. Loss aversion is a tendency where investors are so fearful of losses that they focus on trying to avoid a loss more so than on making gains. The more one experiences losses, the more likely they are to become prone to loss aversion. Research on loss aversion shows that investors feel the pain of a loss more than twice as strongly as they feel the enjoyment of making a profit. The concept of loss aversion has emerged as an implication of prospect theory that investors are not risk-averse, but loss averse. Such a thing occurs because the psychological impacts of losses are greater than those of profits. To put it another way, investors tend to feel more stressed by potential losses in comparison to potential gains with an equivalent value. Therefore, they will be more prudent in investment to reduce the risk of losses (Barberis & Thaler, 2003).

H3: Loss aversion bias will affect investment decisions.

3.4. Overconfidence Bias and Investment Decisions

Another behavioral bias that is also often found among investors is overconfidence. Overconfidence bias means that the individual is outrightly confident of his decisions and he overestimates or exaggerates his ability to perform a task. Decision-makers incline to overestimate the knowledge and information that they possessed, also ignore the public information available. The investors with overconfidence bias override models and data because they convince themselves that they know better. They may not always know better, and by ignoring the early signs of potential damage, they cause themselves more harm than good. (Lichtenstein & Fischhoff, 1977). Baker and Nofsinger (2002) defined overconfidence as a form of excessive self-confidence that the information owned can be utilized properly because of having good analytical skills. In fact, this is only an illusion of belief, due to lack of experience and having a shortcoming in interpreting available information.

In short, overconfidence is a condition in which investors believe and consider their abilities are above the average of other investors and have an unrealistic level of self-evaluation (Odean, 1999; Pompian, 2006). Frischhoff et al. (1977) asserted that in an uncertain world of investment, investors are inclined to make overconfident decisions. Those who are overconfident usually think that they know more than they do, so they tend to believe that they are better or smarter than others (Shiller, 2000). When the number of market participants who are overconfident is large, then the aggregate reactions that occur in the market will be far from being ration8al.

According to Frensidy (2016), an individual’s inclination to be overconfident may be caused by two things. First, except for those who are depressed, everyone positively judges themselves. Second, psychologically, people want to control the situation and their surroundings and believe that they can do that. Further, he revealed that there are four financial implications of this bias. First, investors can take the wrong position in buying and selling shares because they fail to realize that they do not have the advantage of information or analysis. Second, investors are inclined to trade more frequently which results in higher transaction costs. Third, overconfident investors are inclined to set prediction intervals that are too narrow. Finally, overconfident investors will be surprised more often than expected.

A handful of studies have been conducted to investigate the influence of overconfidence bias on the financial market. Overconfidence behavior unconsciously influences investors to do excessive trading (Benos, 1998; Daniel et al., 1998; Graham et al., 2005; Odean, 1999; Pompian, 2006; Toma, 2015; Ullah et al., 2017). Besides affecting the frequency of transactions, overconfidence bias also affects trading volume. The higher the overconfident level, the greater the volume traded (Statman et al., 2003). These results indicate a positive influence of overconfidence bias towards investment decision making. Besides, Bakar and Yi (2016) also revealed that the level of overconfidence that occurs also depends on individual gender.

Those research findings are in line with Pompian (2006) who found that the belief of overconfidence in skills can cause mistakes in decision making that make investors trade excessively. The overconfident investor also tends to overestimate investment returns and underestimate risks. If the actual return is lower than the expected return, they will associate it with an unfortunate condition (Miller, 1975). Overall, these various factors will have a positive impact on investment decisions.

H4: Overconfidence bias will affect investment decisions.

3.5. Optimism Bias and Investment Decisions

Optimism bias often relates to overconfidence bias. Nofsinger (2005) explained that both overconfidence and optimism biases are caused by the same psychological factors – an illusion of knowledge and illusion of control. The former is a condition in which an individual feel highly confident with the information they possessed. It affects his/ her belief in the chance level of success that may be achieved. Such belief then leads to perceived control over the results to be gained (the illusion of control). The illusion of control is the tendency for people to overestimate their ability to control events; for example, it occurs when someone feels a sense of control over outcomes that they demonstrably do not influence. Thus, control illusions are defined as a situation in which people frequently believe that they have influenced the results obtained from an uncontrolled event. When an illusion of knowledge and illusion of control evolve further, there will appear as excessive optimism (Shefrin, 2007).

Shefrin (2007) defined optimism bias as one who inclines to overestimate success (the likelihood of obtaining results as desired) and underestimating the risk of failure. Further, optimism bias is an investor’s expectation or belief that their portfolio performance will always generate a positive return (Hoffmann et al., 2013). The important thing from this bias is that there is a likelihood that investors make investment decisions excessively. The higher level of optimism bias that occurred, the higher investor’s expectation of their portfolio performance. This positive expectation then spurs them to increase the frequency and volume of trading, even though there is a high probability that the actual may deviate from the expectations (Pompian, 2006). Khan et al., (2017) and Ullah et al. (2017) found a relationship between past portfolio yields and the level of investor optimism that had an impact on investment decisions.

H5: Optimism bias will affect investment decisions.

3.6. Herding Behavior and Investment Decisions

Banerjee (1992) and Hirshleifer and Teoh (2003) explained herding behavior as a people behavior that tends to follow the actions of other people rather than following their owned- beliefs or owned-information in the making decision. This behavior is considered irrational behavior as investors decide based on other’s decisions in the market (Altman, 2012). Herding behavior is often found among investors in emerging markets and mostly occurred during market stress situations (Rahayu et al., 2020). According to Humra (2014), herding behavior occurs when a group of investors make investment decisions based on collective information from a group of investors and ignore other information. As a result, when the group majority makes a wrong decision, it will turn to significant market price deviations.

The finding of Chang et al. (2000) showed that herding practices are more prevalent in developing countries, which then is supported by Chiang and Zheng (2010) and Zheng et al. (2017) concerning the herding practices in Asian stock exchanges (China, South Korea, Singapore, Malaysia, and Indonesia). Herd mentality bias refers to investors’ tendency to follow and copy what other investors are doing. They are largely influenced by emotion and instinct, rather than by their own independent analysis. In Indonesia, the research findings related to herding behavior are still contradictive, even though they are tested by the same methods. Sari (2012), and Purba and Faradynawati (2012) revealed there had been herding practices in Indonesia, whereas Narasanto (2012) did not find herding practices. Furthermore, Bowe and Domuta (2004), using the Lakonishok et al. (1992) method, found that herding behavior in the Indonesian Stock Exchange was mostly dominated by foreign investors.

H6: Herding behavior will affect investment decisions.

4. Methodology

The population of this study is investors over the age of 17 years and based in Yogyakarta and based on random sampling that results in 165 respondents. To determine the sample size, we use the Slovin formula. It provides the sample size (n) using the known population size (N) and the acceptable error value (e). Slovin’s formula gives the researcher an idea of how large the sample size needs to be to ensure a reasonable accuracy of results.

\(n=\frac{Z^{2}}{4(\mathrm{Moe})^{2}}\)

Z = Level of confidence, this study uses a 95% confidence level

Moe = The maximum tolerable error rate is 8%

n = sample size

We collect the data using questionnaires based on the 5-Likert scale, with 1 = Strongly Disagree; 2 = Disagree; 3 = Neutral; 4 = Agree; and 5 = Strongly Agree. We define only score 4 and 5 that considered investor decisions are influenced by behavioral bias, otherwise, it does not (Altamimi, 2006). The total number of questions from all variables are 42 questions − 5 questions for anchoring bias, 8 questions for representativeness bias, 5 questions for loss aversion, 7 questions for overconfidence bias, 7 questions for optimism bias, and 4 questions for herding behavior. Six independent variables are used in the model -anchoring bias, representativeness bias, loss aversion, overconfidence bias, optimism bias, and herding behavior, while the dependent variable is investment decisions. The data is first analyzed based on validity and reliability test to validate the questionnaires using Bivariate Pearson correlation (Pearson Product Moment).

\(r_{x y}=\frac{N \sum X Y-\left(\sum X\right)\left(\sum Y\right)}{\sqrt{\left[\left\{N \sum X^{2}-\left(\sum X\right)^{2}\right\}\left\{N \sum Y^{2}-\left(\sum Y\right)^{2}\right\}\right]}}\)

rxy = Pearson Correlation Coefficient

X = Scores for each question or statement item

Y = Scores for total question items or statements

∑X = total scores in X distribution

∑Y = total scores in Y distribution

∑X2 = total squares of each X score

∑Y2 = total squares of each Y score

N = total subjects

The reliability of items that test the degree of stability, consistency, predictive power, and accuracy are measured based on the Cronbach alpha formula:

\(\alpha=\left(\frac{K}{K-1}\right)\left(\frac{S_{r}^{2}-\sum S_{1}^{2}}{S_{x}^{2}}\right)\)

α = Cronbach’ alpha reliability coefficient

K = total question items tested

\(\sum s_{1}^{2}\)= total item score variants

SX2= Variance of test scores (all items)

Then, One sample t-test is used to test the effect of anchoring bias, representativeness bias, loss aversion, overconfidence bias, optimism bias, and herding behavior on investor decisions. The formula for one-sample t-test is used as follows:

\(Z=\frac{\bar{X}-\mu_{x}}{S / \sqrt{n}}\)

5. Results and Discussion

Table 1 displays the information about the characteristics of the respondents. The results of the Pearson Bivariate correlation test on the total questionnaire items indicate that all of them are valid based on the r-value of each item which is greater than the value of the r-table. The Cronbach’s alpha score also shows similar results where the value for each item is greater than 0.6. The score for each variable - anchoring bias, representativeness bias, loss aversion, over-evidence bias, optimism bias, and herding behavior are 0.61, 0.77, 0.67, 0.86, 0.78, and 0.75 respectively. The Kolmogorov- Smirnov test is used to check the normality and it shows that the data is distributed normally. The results of one sample t-test indicate that the average value of each variable is greater than 3.00 and all of the hypotheses are significant at 1% alpha. It indicates that most of the investors in Yogyakarta tend to be affected by anchoring bias, representativeness bias, loss aversion, overconfidence bias, optimism bias, and herding behavior in making investment decisions.

Table 1: Sample Descriptive

Table 2: The Result of One-Sample T-Test

5.1. Anchoring Bias and Investment Decisions

The result of the first hypothesis suggests that there is an inclination of the investors to sell the stocks based on buying price as the reference price. The investors make quick decisions to sell their shares when the selling price exceeds the buying price. Besides buying price, the highest price that was achieved during a certain period also becomes the reference price. Besides, investors decide to buy stocks based on the past stocks’ performance which means the investors overestimate their own opinions and expertise. This finding is in line with that of Frensidy (2016), Vijaya (2014), Rekik and Boujelbene (2013), Luong and Doan (2011), and Masomi and Ghayekhloo (2010).

5.2. Representativeness Bias and Investment Decisions

The result of the second hypothesis testing indicates that representativeness bias has a significant influence on investment decisions. Investors tend to make decisions simply based on limited information from the surroundings and ignore other information or the important events that may happen in the future. Hence, they are less prepared for unexpected events or information. They also consider that past performance as the best indicator to predict future performance. The representativeness bias further supports the notion that people fail to properly calculate and utilize probability in their decisions. The research finding is consistent with Toma (2015), Vijaya (2016), and Virigineni and Bhaskara (2017).

5.3. Loss Aversion and Investment Decisions

The third hypothesis result shows that investors are prudent in deciding to buy or sell the shares to avoid the loss. They focus more on avoiding the losses instead of gaining higher profits. Very often, stocks are bought without much research. So, once the stock price goes up, investors fear that it may go down as fast as it went up. Such thinking makes them sell the stocks too soon. Then come instances where the stock price has gone down after an investor has bought it. This tends to happen when the primary reason for buying the stock was a recent upsurge. Hence, when the value of their portfolio investment decreases, they prefer to retain it as they hope that it would increase to the previous price in the future. On the other hand, they tend to sell their stock so early when the investment value increases. These findings support the concept of disposition effect and are in line with that of Luong and Doan (2011), Ngoc (2014), Khan (2017), Kimeu et al. (2016), and Rekik and Boujelbene (2013).

5.4. Overconfidence Bias and Investment Decisions

We also find in this study that overconfidence bias has a significant influence on investment decisions. Considering that the major respondents are college students, there is a high level of probability that they tend to have a higher level of enthusiasm and motivation to get into the investment world. However, enthusiasm and motivation themselves are not enough to be a good investor. They need to develop more investment skills and broaden the knowledge of investment which they do not have enough. Stock investment is a longterm investment that has the highest risk compared with other types of investments, such as mutual funds or bonds. This is worth noting for young investors who are very vulnerable to overconfidence bias. This empirical finding is consistent with Toma (2015), Bakar and Yi (2016), and Ullah et al. (2017).

5.5. Optimism Bias and Investment Decisions

The result of the fifth hypothesis also describes that optimism bias affects investment decisions significantly. The optimism bias is an expectation or belief that the future performance will always better than the past return (Hoffmann et al., 2013). As the respondents are dominated by the young investors, who are highly susceptible to be overconfident, it will be followed by a high level of optimism. Overconfidence and optimism biases are caused by the illusion of knowledge and illusion of control. The illusion of knowledge is a condition where a person feels very confident about the information he/she has so that it has an impact on his/her belief in their chance of success. It supports by the empirical finding of Khan et al. (2017), Fatima and Waqas (2016), and Ullah et al. (2017).

5.6. Herding Behavior and Investment Decisions

This study also found that herding behavior has a significant influence on investment decisions. It indicates that investors tend to rely on collective information from other investors rather than personal information. In this respect, the investors react impulsively to the changes found in others’ decisions as they prefer others’ investment choices to their own choices. They put little attention on the company’s prospects and believe more about what others decide in the market. This finding is in line with the studies of Vijaya (2014), Ngoc (2014), Ranjbar et al. (2014), and Kumar and Goyal (2015).

6. Conclusion

Our research findings suggest that anchoring bias, representativeness bias, loss aversion, overconfidence bias, optimism bias, and herding behavior affect significantly the investor’s decisions. There are a few opportunities for much more comprehensive research on investors’ behavioral biases.

참고문헌

  1. Ackert, L. F., & Deaves R. (2010). Behavioral finance psychology, decision making, and markets. Cincinnati, OH: South-Western, Cengage Learning.
  2. Al-Mansour, B. Y. (2020). Cryptocurrency market: Behavioral finance perspective. Journal of Asian Finance, Economics, and Business, 7(12), 159-165. https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2020.vol7.no12.159
  3. Altamimi, H. A. H. (2006). Factors influencing individual investor behavior: An empirical study of the UAE financial market. The Business Review. 5(2), 225-232. https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Hussein_Al-Tamimi/publication/257936341_Factors_Influencing_Individual_Investor_Behaviour_An_Empirical_study_of_the_UAE_Financial_MarketsThe_Business_Review_Cambridge_Vol5No_2225-232_2006/links/00b4953ab9c4e8ba85000000.pdf
  4. Altman, M. (2012). Behavioral economics for dummies. Mississauga: John Wiley & Sons.
  5. Asri, M. (2013). Behavioral finance. Yogyakarta: BPFE-Yogyakarta.
  6. Bakar, S., & Yi, A. C. (2016). The impact of psychological factors on investors' decision-making in the Malaysian stock market: a case of Klang Valley and Pahang. Procedia Economics and Finance, 35, 319-328. https://doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(16)00040-X
  7. Baker, H. K., & Nofsinger J. R. (2002). Psychological bias of investors. Financial Services Review. 11(2), 97-116. https://scinapse.io/papers/172315172
  8. Banerjee, A. V. (1992). A simple model of herd behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(3), 797-817. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118364
  9. Barberis, N., & Thaler, R. (2003). A survey of behavioral finance. Handbook of the Economics of Finance, 25(2), 1053-1128. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0102(03)01027-6
  10. Benos, A. V. (1998). Aggressiveness and survival of overconfident traders. Journal of Financial Markets, 1(3-4), 353-383. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1386-4181(97)00010-4
  11. Bowe, M., & Domuta, D. (2004). Investor herding during the financial crisis: A clinical study of the Jakarta Stock Exchange. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 12(4), 387-418. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.pacfin.2003.09.003
  12. Chang, E. C., Cheng, J. W., & Khorana, A. (2000). An examination of herd behavior in equity markets. International Perspective Journal of Banking and Finance, 24, 1651-1679. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0378-4266(99)00096-5
  13. Chen, G., Kim, K. A., & Nofsinger, J. R. (2007). Trading performance, disposition effect, overconfidence, representativeness bias, and experience of emerging market investors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 20(4), 425-451. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.957504
  14. Chiang, T. C., & Zheng, D. (2010). An empirical analysis of herd behavior in global stock markets. Journal of Banking and Finance, 34, 1911-1921. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.014
  15. Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., & Subrahmanyam, A. (1998). Investor psychology and security market under and overreaction. Journal of Finance, 53(6), 1839-1885. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00077
  16. De Bondt, W. F. M., & Thaler, R. (1985). Does the stock market overreact? Journal of Finance, 40(3), 793-805. https://doi.org/10.2307/2327804
  17. De Bondt, W., Muradoglu, G., Shefrin, S., & Staikouras, S. K. (2008). Behavioral finance: Quo Vadis? Journal of Applied Finance, 18(2), 1-15. https://ssrn.com/abstract=269814
  18. Fama, E. F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review on theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383-417. https://doi.org/10.2307/2325486
  19. Fatima, N., & Waqas, M. (2016). Impact of optimistic bias and availability bias on investment decision making with the moderating role of financial literacy. First International Conference of Indigenous Resource Management challenges and Opportunities at University of Management Sciences and Information Technology Kotli, Azaad Kashmir 14-15 April 2016 (pp. 1-28).
  20. Franses, P. H. (2007). Experts adjusting model-based forecast and the law of small numbers (Report No. EI 2007-42). Econometric Institute, Erasmus University Rotterdam. https://repub.eur.nl/pub/10563
  21. Frensidy, B. (2016). Agile and tactical in the capital market: Armed with behavioral finance. Jakarta: Salemba Empat.
  22. Frischhoff, B., Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1977). Knowing with certainty: The appropriateness of extreme confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 3(4), 552-564. https://doi.org/10.1037/0096-1523.3.4.552
  23. Fromlet, H. (2001). Behavioral finance-theory and practical application. Business Economics, 36(3), 63-69. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2329573
  24. Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., & Huang, H. (2005). Investor competence, trading frequency, and home bias (NBER Working Paper 11426). National Bureau of Economic Research https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w11426/w11426.pdf
  25. Hirschey, M., & Nofsinger R. J. (2008). Investment: Analysis and behavioral. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
  26. Hirshleifer, D., & Teoh, S. H. (2003). Herd behavior and cascading in capital markets: A review and synthesis. European Financial Management, 9(1), 25-66. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-036X.00207
  27. Hoffmann, A. O., Post, T., & Pennings M. E. (2013). Individual investor perception and behavior during the financial crisis. Journal of Banking and Finance, 37(1), 60-74. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.08.007
  28. Humra, Y. (2014). Behavioral finance: An introduction to the principles governing investor behavior in stock markets. International Journal of Financial Management, 5(2), 23-30. http://iaset.us/download/archives/2-35-1456481625-3.%20Abstract.pdf
  29. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263-291. https://doi.org/10.2307/1914185
  30. ahneman, D., & Riepe, M. W. (1998). Aspects of investor psychology: Beliefs, preferences, and biases investment advisors should know about. Journal of Portfolio Management, 24(4), 52-65. https://doi.org/10.3905/jpm.1998.409643
  31. Kartini, K., & Nuris, F. N. (2015). The influence of illusions of control, overconfidence, and emotional biases on investment decisions. Jurnal Inovasi dan Kewirausahaan, 4(2), 115-123. https://doi.org/10.20885/ajie.vol4.iss2.art6
  32. Khan, M. U. (2017). Impact of availability bias and loss aversion bias on investment decision making, moderating role of risk perception. Journal of Modern Developments in General Management & Administration, 1(1), 17-28. http://www.impactjournals.us/download/archives/1-82-1502108083-3.
  33. Khan, M. T., Chong, L. L., & Tan, S. H. (2017). Perception of past portfolio returns, optimism, and financial decisions. Review of Behavioral Finance, 9(1), 79-98. https://doi.org/10.1108/RBF02-2016-0005
  34. Kimeu, C. N., Anyago. W., & Rotich, G. (2016). Behavioural factors influencing investment decisions among individual investors in Nairobi Securities Exchange. The Strategic Journal of Business & Change Management, 3(4), 1243-1258. http://www.strategicjournals.com/index.php/journal/article/view/377
  35. Kumar, S., & Goyal, N. (2015). Behavioral biases in investment decision making; A systematic literature review. Qualitative Research in Financial Markets, 7(1), 88-108. https://doi.org/10.1108/QRFM-07-2014-0022
  36. Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1992). The impact of institutional trading on, stock price. Journal of Financial Economics, 32(1), 23-43. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(92)90023-Q
  37. Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1994). Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk. Journal of Finance, 49(5), 1541-1578. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1994.tb04772
  38. Lichtenstein, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1977). Do those who know more also know more about how much they know? Organizational Behavior and Human Performance. 20(2), 159-83. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224379202900304
  39. Lintner, J. (1965). Security prices, risk, and maximum gains from diversification. Journal of Finance, 20(4), 587-615. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1965.tb02930
  40. Luong, L. P., & Doan, T. T. H. (2011). Behavioral individual investors' decision making and performance a survey at the Ho Chi Minh stock exchange [Master Thesis, Umeå School of Business]. http://umu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:423263/FULLTEXT02.pdf
  41. Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77-91. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525
  42. Marsden, A., Veeraraghavan, M., & Ye. M. (2008). Heuristics of representativeness, anchoring, and adjustment, and leniency: impact on earnings forecasts by Australian analysts. Quarterly Journal of Finance and Accounting, 47(2), 83-102. http://hdl.handle.net/2292/8518
  43. Masomi, S. R., & Ghayekhloo, S. (2010). Consequences of human behaviors' in economic: The effects of behavioral factors in investment decision making at Teheran Stock Exchange. International Conference on Business and Economics Research, 1, 1-4. http://ipedr.com/vol1/50-B10068.pdf
  44. Miller, D. T. (1975). Self-serving biases in the attribution of causality: Fact or fiction. Psychological Bulletin, 82(2), 213-225. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0076486
  45. Mossin, J. (1969). Security pricing and investment criteria in competitive markets. American Economic Review, 59(5), 749-756. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1810673
  46. Narasanto, I. T. (2012). Herding behavior an experience in Indonesian stock market (No, 5589) [Master Thesis, Perpustakaan Universitas Gadjah Mada, Yogyakarata] http://etd.repository.ugm.ac.id/home/detail_pencarian/55899
  47. Ngoc, L. T. B. (2014). The behavior pattern of individual investors in the stock market. International Journal of Business and Management, 9(1), 1-16. https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v9n1p1
  48. Nofsinger, J. R. (2005). Social mood and financial economics. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 6(3), 144-160. https://doi.org/10.1207/s15427579jpfm0603_4
  49. Odean, T. (1999). Do investors trade too much? American Economic Review, 89, 1279-98. https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.94143
  50. Olsen. R. A. (1998). Behavioral finance and its implication for stock price volatility. Financial Analyst Journal, 52(2), 10-18. https://doi.org/10.2469/faj.v54.n2.2161
  51. Pompian, M. M. (2006). Behavioral finance and wealth management. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
  52. Purba, A. V., & Faradynawati, A. A. (2012). An examination of herd behavior in the Indonesian Stock Market. Indonesian Capital Market Review, 4(1), 1-10. https://doi/org/10.21002/icmr.v4i1.985
  53. Rahayu, S., Rohman, A., & Harto, P. (2020). Herding behavior model in investment decision on Emerging Markets: Experimental in Indonesia. Journal of Asian Finance, Economics, and Business, 8(1), 53-59. https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2021.vol8.no1.053
  54. Ranjbar, M. H., Abedini, B., & Jamali, M. (2014). Analyzing the effective behavioral factors on the investors' performance in Tehran Stock Exchange (TSE). International Journal of Technical Research and Applications, 2(8), 2320-8163.
  55. Rekik, Y. M., & Boujelbene, Y. (2013). Determinants of individual investors' behaviors: Evidence from Tunisian Stock Market. IOSR Journal of Business and Management, 8(2), 109-119. https://doi.org/10.9790/487X-082109119
  56. Ritter, J. R. (2003). Behavioral finance. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 11(4), 429-437. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0927-538X(03)00048-9
  57. Sari, A. M. (2012). Herding behavior in Indonesia and the impact of the global stock market. Master Thesis. Yogyakarta: FEB UGM
  58. Sha, N., & Ismail, M. Y. (2020). Behavioral investor types and financial market players in Oman. Journal of Asian Finance, Economics, and Business, 8(1), 285-294. https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2021.vol8.no1.285
  59. Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under the condition of risk. Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425-442. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1964.tb02865
  60. Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1985). The disposition to sell winners too early and riding losers too long. Journal of Finance, 40(3), 777-790. https://doi.org/10.2307/2327802
  61. Shefrin, H. (2000). Beyond greed and fear: Understanding behavioral finance and the psychology of investing. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
  62. Shefrin H. (2002). Behavioral decision making, forecasting, game theory, and role-play. International Journal of Forecasting, 18(3), 375-382. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0169-2070(02)00021-3
  63. Shefrin, H. (2007). Behavioral corporate finance: Decision that creates value. McGraw-Hill/Irwin
  64. Shiller, R. J. (1987). Investor behavior in the October 1987 stock market crash: Survey evidence (Working Paper 2446). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w2446
  65. Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational exuberance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  66. Statman, M., Thorley, S., & Vorkink, K. (2003). Investor overconfidence and trading volume. Review of Financial Studies, 19(4), 1531-1565. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.168472
  67. Subash, R. (2012). Role of behavioral finance in portfolio investment decision: Evidence from India [Master Thesis, Charles University in Prague]. https://is.cuni.cz/webapps/zzp/detail/110165/?lang=en
  68. Toma, F. M. (2015). Behavioral biases of the investment decisions of Romanian investors on the Bucharest Stock Exchange. Procedia Economics and Finance, 32, 200-207. https://doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(15)01383-0
  69. Treynor. J. L. (1961). Market value, time, and risk [Unpublished manuscript]. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2600356
  70. Tversky, A., & Kahneman D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, New Series, 185(4157), 1124-1131.
  71. Ullah, I., Ullah. A., & Rehman, N. U. (2017). Impact of overconfidence and optimism on investment decision. International Journal of Information, Business, and Management, 9(2), 231-243. http://ejournal.ukrida.ac.id/ojs/index.php/Akun/article/download/1802/1821/
  72. Vijaya, E. (2014). An empirical analysis of influential factors on investment behavior of retail investors' in the Indian Stock Market: A behavioral perspective. International Journal in Management and Social Science, 2(12), 296-308. https://www.indianjournals.com/ijor.aspx?target=ijor:ijmss&volume=2&issue=12&article=027
  73. Vijaya, E. (2016). An empirical analysis on the behavioral pattern of Indian retail equity investors. Journal of Resources Development and Management, 16, 103-112. https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/234696209.pdf
  74. Virigineni, M., & Bhaskara, R. (2017). Contemporary developments in behavioral finance. International Journal of Economics and Financial, 7(1), 448-459. https://www.econjournals.com/index.php/ijefi/article/view/3809
  75. Yoong, J. (2010). Making financial education more effective: lessons from behavioral economics (Working paper Session II). Behavioral Economics and Financial Education.
  76. Zheng, D., Li. H., & Chiang, T. C. (2017). Herding with industries: Evidence from Asian stock markets. International Review of Economics and Finance, 51, 487-509. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2017.07.005