1. Introduction
Environmental uncertainty, which refers to the fluctuations in availability and the price of raw resources, provides profound threats with manufacturers (Williamson, 1985; Trevino & Kerr, 2015). Therefore, manufacturers try to rely on interfirm mechanisms as a countermeasure to such uncertainties (Cai, Yang, & Hu, 2009; Santoro & McGrill, 2005). Thus environmental uncertainty is the greatest contextual factor affecting interfirm relationships (Palmatier, Dant, & Grewal, 2007).
Interfirm relationship is a complex network that their environments form many parts of the governance mechanism. Persuasive theories have so far developed in marketing field, which demonstrate how exchange partners develop governance mechanisms in an uncertain situations. One of the most persuasive theories is transaction cost analysis. Transaction cost analysis has proven useful tool in explaining governance mechanism (Stump & Heide, 1996).
Transaction cost theorists argue that the asymmetry of the information exchanged between the manufacturer and the supplier arises from the environmental uncertainty. For instance, the better-informed party is more likely to have opportunistic behavior (Pavlou, Liang, & Xue, 2007; Klein, Frazier, & Roth, 1990). Manufacturers therefore need to reduce supplier opportunistic behavior by adopting unilateral governance, the extent to which manufacturers unilaterally control supplier decisions (Stump & Heide, 1996; Jap & Anderson, 2003; Bello & Gilliland, 1997).
On the other hand, relational contract theorists propose that manufacturers in uncertain environments perform via bilateral governance is defined as the reliance on a shared set of implicit behavioral principles for the coordination of interfirm exchange partners (Heide, 1994; Noordewier, John, & Nevin, 1990; Cannon, Achrol, & Gundlach, 2000).
It has not yet been decided which governance mechanism should be chosen to better manage relations with exchange partners in an uncertain environment. The purpose of this study is to iron out two opposing suggestions in the uncertain environment; transaction cost theory (unilateral governance) and relational contract theory (bilateral governance).
This study introduces two governance mechanisms; vertical control, an unilateral governance mechanism and flexibility, a bilateral governance mechanism and suggest that interfirm benevolence serve as a moderating variable in explaining the relationships between environmental uncertainty and governance mechanisms. Interfirm benevolence affects the level of information asymmetry induced by environmental uncertainty and stimulates the exchange of information. In this regard, it is predictable that interfirm benevolence may be a critical factor affecting the adoption of governance mechanisms in an uncertain environment. This paper suggests that party with benevolence to their partners rely on bilateral governance, while those without benevolence may adopt unilateral governance.
This study develops the conceptual framework based on effects of environmental uncertainty on governance mechanisms to investigate the impact of interfirm network factor. In this way, this study contributes to network governance study and network characteristic study at the same moment.
In the next section, the theoretical background for environmental uncertainty, governance mechanisms and interfirm benevolence will be discussed. Then the research propositions are developed. Figure 1. presents the proposed framework.
Figure 1: Conceptual Framework
2. Review of Literature and Propositions
2.1. Marketing Environment and Environmental Uncertainty
Generally, marketing environment means that the actors outside marketing affect management's ability of marketing to build relationships with target customers successfully (Kotler & Armstrong 2010). Kotler and Armstrong (2010) explained that the marketing environment consists of a microenvironment and a macroenvironment.
The microenvironment is made up of the actors close to the firm that affect its ability to serve its customers (e.g., the company, intermediaries, suppliers, consumers, competitors, and publics) while the macroenvironment is made up of the larger societal actors that affect the microenvironment (e.g., demographic, natural, economic, technological, political, and culture environments).
2.2.1. The Company's Microenvironment
Marketing managers need to build and maintain relationships with customers by creating customer satisfaction. But, they cannot do this alone. [Table 1] demonstrates the main actors in the microenvironment.
Table 1: Actors in the Microenvironmnent
Source: Kotler and Armstrong(2010)
2.2.2. The Company's macroenvironment
The macroenvironment consists of larger forces that impact on the actors in the macroenvironment. [Table 2] shows the six main forces in the company's macroenvironment.
Table 2: Main Forces in the Company's Macroenvironment
Source: Kotler and Armstrong (2010).
2.2.3. Internal and external environments
When the environment is defined in this way, there are factors within the boundaries of the organization that should be considered as part of the environment. Therefore, a differentiation is made between internal and external environment (Duncan, 1972). The internal environment means that relevant social and physical factors within the boundaries of the organization which are taken directly into consideration in making decision. The external environment means that relevant social and physical factors outside the boundaries of the organization which are taken directly into consideration (Duncan, 1972). The list of environmental factors presented in [Table 3].
Table 3: Factors comprising the organization's internal and external environment
Source: Duncan (1972).
Following Anderson et al. (1994)'s definition, environment is defined as anything not part of the organization itself. In this study, environmental influence includes all impact which is not arose from the organization itself in exchange relationships. The environment includes everything that can affect the company in any way. Therefore, it can exist inside or outside of the network surrounding the focal company.
2.2.4. Environmental Uncertainty
Environmental uncertainty is an important characteristic of the environment (Stump & Heide, 1996). In this study, environmental uncertainty is defined as the extent to which environments rapidly, as well as the difficulty in predicting about the environments accurately (Klein et al., 1990; Jeon, 2018). Because of having these features, the manufacturer in uncertain environment is likely to make predictions of resources inaccurately, and thus there is no certainty about the amount of resources or when the resource will arrive (Roh, Kim, Yoo, & Kim, 2015).
Exchange parties confront an uncertain environment experiences uncertainty when it does not have relevant information or when there are too numerous situations that are coincidental or hard to predict (Eisingerich, Bell, & Tracey, 2010; Argote 1982; Stump & Heide 1996). As a result, it is difficult for the parties to forecast accurately about the real status of the environment (Frazier & Antia 1995).
Environmental uncertainty often causes opportunistic behavior among exchange partners for its interest by taking advantage of this uncertainty (Luo, 2007). Opportunism is self-interest-seeking behavior along with guile (Williamson, 1985). Opportunistic behavior includes subtle forms of dishonest behaviors such as withholding or avoiding responsibility, cheating, and distorting information of market. For example, if there is an unexpected shortage of parts in the market, perhaps the supplier may impose an overinflated price on the manufacturer. In turn, opportunism can raise total transaction costs.
In case of an exchange partner's potential opportunism under uncertain market conditions, exchange partners have to adapt to uncertainty rapidly (Stump & Heide, 1996). Exchange partners should rely on an interfirm governance mechanism that is best proper for conditions reflecting uncertainty (Stump & Heide, 1996). For instance, environmental uncertainty enables exchange partners to monitor closely and control the exchange partners' potential opportunism. Also norms are developed among exchange partners in such an uncertain environment.
2.3. Interfirm Governance Mechanisms
Various researches have explored the governance mechanisms existing between firms (e.g. Heide, 1994; Judge, 2010) and within firms (Ouchi, 1979). Research has identified two major types of governance mechanisms: unilateral and bilateral governance mechanisms.
The difference between unilateral and bilateral governance mechanisms is based upon the extent to which both exchange parties influence another partner's decision-making (Bello & Gilliland, 1997). While the bilateral governance mechanism is based on the premise that the both exchange partners will participate in decision-making, the unilateral governance mechanism relies only on manufacturer's decision-making ability (Gilliland, Bello, & Gundlach, 2010).
This study adopted two governance mechanisms such as vertical control and flexibility. Vertical control indicates the unilateral governance mechanism, on the other hand the norm of flexibility indicates the bilateral governance mechanism. Because these two governance mechanisms help manufacturer with obtaining information on the suppliers, they play a role as proper methods for reducing the risk related with vested benevolence.
The unilateral governance mechanism is based on the efforts of the controlling parties influencing the behavior of the partner and uses external measures, such as results or actions of the partner (Heide & John, 1988; Bello & Gilliland, 1997; Stump & Heide, 1996; Celly & Frazie, 1996). Vertical control involves examining the performance of suppliers in terms of inventory or delivery levels. As a result, vertical control of the supplier provides the manufacturer with safeguards that are critical to detecting the supplier's opportunistic behavior, thereby protecting the manufacturer's interests.
Manufacturers in environmental uncertainty have difficulty in accurately forecasting the supply of resources from their suppliers. This uncertain environment makes it possible for suppliers to take opportunistic behavior by taking advantage of the uncertainties that manufacturers have (Luo, 2007). Opportunism is self-interestseeking behavior coupled with guile (Williamson, 1985). This opportunism increases the total transaction cost, so manufacturers must closely and directly control their partners' behavior. Thus, the following is proposed.
H1. Environmental Uncertainty will positively influence on the unilateral governance mechanisms of channel firms.
The bilateral governance mechamism is based on community rather than the individual goals of both parties (Khan, 2011; Gundlach & Achrol, 1993). The bilateral governance mechanism depends on relational norm (Weitz & Jap, 1995; Lusch & Brown, 1996) to encourage efforts for mutual benefit between the manufacturer and the supplier (Weitz & Jap, 1995).
Bilateral governance regulates proper behavior of the manufacturer and the supplier (Heide, 1994). That is, bilateral governance gives order to what otherwise might be uncertain and ambiguous situations. Therefore, the bilateral governance guides partners to act in a cooperative manner to achieve common goals.
Bilateral governance is based on a manufacturer-supplier relationship that verifies which types of behavior are advisable or unadvisable, rather than on directly monitoring partner's behavior (Griffith & Myers, 2005). Therefore, bilateral governance promotes the formulation of relational norms that compel parties to pursue mutual benefit for both manufacturers and suppliers (Gundlach & Achrol, 1993). For example, a typical relational norm is the flexibility. The exchange partners who select bilateral governance have a shared principle, so they are flexible in coping with the sudden demands of their partners in an uncertain environment (Noordewier et al., 1990). The flexibility indicates the expectation that each party will try to adapt to a series of new contracts and attempts to change the situation without renegotiation (Young, Sapienza, & Baumer, 2003). For instance, if a strike or flood prevents the supplier from keeping up with the equipment part deadline, the supplier will ask the manufacturer to accept the late delivery.
A manufacturer in an uncertain environment might find it difficult to keep up the transaction if the supplier makes unstable supply. Bilateral governance cannot develop between manufacturers and suppliers in this uncertain environment because manufacturers can attempt to switch between multiple suppliers to secure parts.
H2. Environmental Uncertainty will negatively influence on the bilateral governance mechanisms of channel firms.
2.4. The Moderating Effect of Interfirm Benevolence
Interfirm benevolence, the belief of a manufacturer that the exchange partner will not only behave leading to positive outcomes, but will also avoid behaviors leading to negative outcomes (Aurifeille & Medlin, 2009). Interfirm benevolence increases the willingness to rely on an exchange partner whose action is not directly under other control (Moorman, Zaltman, & Deshpande, 1992). Also interfirm benevolence increases the willingness to take care of other partner's needs (Medlin & Quester, 2002). Benevolence develops the relationship effectively between manufacturer-supplier relationships by reducing the costs of negotiation (Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone, 1998), enhancing information change (Zand, 1972), encouraging cooperation (Schurr & Ozanne, 1985), facilitating the long-term orientation among partners (Doney & Cannon, 1997; Ganesan, 1994), and leading to better performance (Jap, 1999).
Interfirm benevolence is part of a vulnerability in the manufacturer's relationship with the supplier (Şengün, 2010). For example, manufacturers who trust suppliers to supply on time might experience negative consequences if suppliers fail to fulfill the contract. Benevolent party has potential vulnerabilities in the opportunistic behavior of exchange partners (Elangovan & Shapiro, 1998; Andaleeb, 1992). Suppliers can gain short-term benefits from opportunistic behavior. For example, when a component has a volatile supply, it can be an edge of uncertainty by selling it to alternative buyers in the market. While the manufacturer believes that the supply of the parts is still scarce, a suggestion to increase profit margin can be sold to alternative buyers when purchasing parts. The result of such opportunistic supplier behavior is to make it difficult for manufacturers to reach optimal results and to lower the level of commitment offered by manufacturers within the relationship.
Benevolent party must implement mechanisms to prevent the other party from violating their benevolence, because a benevolent party is vulnerable to the exchange party (Yoon & Kim, 2014). Exchange parties need to consider interfirm governance mechanisms to protect themselves from unbelievable exchange partners (Stump & Heide, 1996; Heide, 1994).
Interfirm benevolence function as a moderator that influences the effect of environmental uncertainty on governance mechanisms. When the manufacturer expects its supplier to be reliable, the perception of uncertainty is reduced (Moorman et al., 1992). The opposite is also possible. If the manufacturer does not have interfirm benevolence for the supplier, the manufacturer will vertically control whether the supplier behaves opportunistically. Thus,
H3: Interfirm benevolence will moderate the relationship between environmental uncertainty and unilateral governance mechanism.
The presence of interfirm benevolence among exchange partners allows for more accurate and timely information (Denize & Young, 2007). The information allows manufacturers to better understand their suppliers. Manufacturers who have no interfirm benevolence on suppliers do not provide appropriate information to their suppliers, but they also provide distorted information, making it difficult to cooperative problem solving (Dirks & Ferrin, 2001). In this situation, bilateral governance is difficult to develop due to the distrust of the information the manufacturer has obtained from the supplier. As a result, Manufacturers who do not have interfirm benevolence on suppliers cannot rely on bilateral governance in dealing with uncertain environments. Therefore, it is proposed that
H4: Interfirm benevolence will moderate the relationship between environmental uncertainty and bilateral governance mechanism.
3. Discussion
The main purpose of this study is demonstrates situations in which different mechanisms function under uncertain environmental conditions. The paper proposes that the environmental uncertainty will have a positive impact on unilateral governance. However, the environmental uncertainty will have a negative impact on bilateral governance.
In terms of role of interfirm benevolence, interfirm benevolence provides a better understanding of how governance mechanisms can develop in an uncertain supply markets. First, if the manufacturer has no interfirm benevolence for the supplier, the manufacturer will respond to market uncertainty with unilateral governance (i.e., vertical control). When the manufacturers have interfirm benevolence in the suppliers, however, the effect of environmental uncertainty on unilateral governance is mitigated. Next, when there is no interfirm benevolence in the relationship between the exchange partners, flexible bilateral governance is unlikely to develop in an uncertain environment. However, when interfirm benevolence is included in the relationship between exchange partners, environmental uncertainty will no longer interfere with the development of bilateral governance (i.e., flexibility).
In summary, the results of this study suggest that manufacturers should consider the level of interfirm benevolence that they give to their suppliers to choose the proper governance mechanism to address environmental uncertainty. In an uncertain environment, manufacturers should consider choosing a unilateral governance if they do not have benevolence to their suppliers. Conversely, if a manufacturer has a benevolence for their suppliers, then bilateral governance should be considered to respond timely to uncertain markets.
3.1. Theoretical Implications
On the contrary to previous network researches, this study has several contributions to research in this field. First, while previous network researches in this field bassed on the interaction of business relationships to achieve individual interest (Wuyts & Van den Bulte, 2012), the current study focuses on the effect of network structure. By focusing on a specific network structure, this study make it easy to understand how macro-level environment influences firm's actions. Second, transaction cost analysis suggests that exchange partners should choose proper interfirm governance mechanism to cope with an uncertain environment. Exchange partners in an uncertain environment must control their partners vertically to improve performance. This study developed a more comprehensive theoretical framework by presenting the transaction cost theory with relationship contract theory. The framework proposes that those theories affect interfirm governance mechanisms together. The results suggest that manufacturers should keep in mind not only environmental uncertainty, but also the interfirm structure so as to build an appropriate governance mechanism.
3.2. Practical Implications
Manufacturers need to select and apply the most appropriate governance mechanisms according to their circumstances. Especially, for manufacturers who have interfirm benevolence to their suppliers, the manufacturer must use the relational norm of flexibility to respond to market changes in a timely manner. In order to cope with uncertain market demand, manufacturer should use the flexibility in their relationships with suppliers. Based on the interfirm benevolence between exchange partners, they will be able to response flexibly to uncertain demand for markets. As a results, bilateral governane contributes to better channel performance for manufacturers (Noordewier et al., 1990; Aulakh, Kotabe, & Sahay, 1996).
3.3. Limitations and Further Research
This study includes some limitations and several future researches. First, this study focuses only on the moderating effect of interfirm benevolence in the impact of environmental uncertainty on manufacturer's decisions of governance mechanisms. However, manufacturers' governance decisions can be influenced by other factors (i.e., network embeddedness, strong tie, weak tie).
Second, even though this paper concentrates on improving the governance mechanism selection process, it does not assess the performance of manufacturer under conditions of uncertain environments. Because the propositions are based on the assumption that the Exchange parties adopt the most efficient governance mechanism structure, it may be better to evaluate how each governance mechanism structure contributes to the manufacturer's performance. Therefore, in future studies, it is necessary to investigate the effect of each governance mechanism structure on performance in an uncertain environment and various level of interfirm benevolence.
Finally, This study does not explicitly suggest what is the most appropriate governance mechanism in situations where environmental uncertainty is low or environmental uncertainty is high. Thus, future research needs to be conducted as a continuum rather than a choice of governance mechanisms. The continuum is located where it can contribute to optimal governance mechanism in the present ambiguous location halfway between vertical control and flexibility.
References
- Andaleeb, S. S. (1992). The trust concept: Research issues for channels of distribution. Research in marketing, 11(1), 1-34.
- Argote, L. (1982). Input uncertainty and organizational coordination in hospital emergency units. Administrative science quarterly, 27, 420-434. https://doi.org/10.2307/2392320
- Aulakh, P. S., Kotabe, M., & Sahay, A. (1996). Trust and performance in cross-border marketing partnerships: A behavioral approach. Journal of international business studies, 27(5), 1005-1032. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8490161
- Aurifeille, J. M., & Medlin, C. (2009). Dimensions of inter-firm trust: Benevolence and credibility. Nova Science Publishers.
- Bello, D. C., & Gilliland, D. I. (1997). The effect of output controls, process controls, and flexibility on export channel performance. The Journal of Marketing, 61(1), 22-38. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224299706100103
- Cai, S., Yang, Z., & Hu, Z. (2009). Exploring the governance mechanisms of quasi-integration in buyer- supplier relationships. Journal of Business Research, 62(6), 660-666. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2008.02.004
- Cannon, J. P., Achrol, R. S., & Gundlach, G. T. (2000). Contracts, norms, and plural form governance. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 28(2), 180-194. https://doi.org/10.1177/0092070300282001
- Celly, K. S., & Frazier, G. L. (1996). Outcome-based and behavior-based coordination efforts in channel relationships. Journal of Marketing Research, 33(2), 200-210. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224379603300207
- Denize, S., & Young, L. (2007). Concerning trust and information. Industrial Marketing Management, 36(7), 968-982. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2007.06.004
- Dirks, K. T., & Ferrin, D. L. (2001). The role of trust in organizational settings. Organization science, 12(4), 450-467. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.12.4.450.10640
- Doney, P. M., & Cannon, J. P. (1997). An examination of the nature of trust in buyer-seller relationships. Journal of Marketing, 61(2), 35-51. https://doi.org/10.2307/1251829
- Duncan, R. B. (1972). Characteristics of organizational environments and perceived environmental uncertainty. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(3), 313-327 https://doi.org/10.2307/2392145
- Eisingerich, A. B., Bell, S. J., & Tracey, P. (2010). How can clusters sustain performance? The role of network strength, network openness, and environmental uncertainty. Research policy, 39(2), 239-253. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2009.12.007
- Elangovan, A. R., & Shapiro, D. L. (1998). Betrayal of trust in organizations. Academy of Management Review, 23(3), 547-566. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1998.926626
- Frazier, G. L., & Antia, K. D. (1995). Exchange relationships and interfirm power in channels of distribution. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 23(4), 321-326. https://doi.org/10.1177/009207039502300412
- Ganesan, S. (1994). Determinants of Long-Term Orientation in Buyer-Seller Relationships. The Journal of Marketing, 58, 1-19. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224299405800201
- Gilliland, D. I., Bello, D. C., & Gundlach, G. T. (2010). Control-based channel governance and relative dependence. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 38(4), 441-455. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-009-0183-8
- Griffith, D. A., & Myers, M. B. (2005). The performance implications of strategic fit of relational norm governance strategies in global supply chain relationships. Journal of International Business Studies, 36(3), 254-269. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400131
- Gundlach, G. T., & Achrol, R. S. (1993). Governance in exchange: Contract law and its alternatives. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 12(2), 141-155. https://doi.org/10.1177/074391569101200201
- Heide, J. B. (1994). Interorganizational governance in marketing channels. Journal of Marketing, 58(1), 71-85. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224299405800106
- Heide, J. B., & John, G. (1988). The role of dependence balancing in safeguarding transaction-specific assets in conventional channels. Journal of Marketing, 52(1), 20-35. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224298805200103
- Jap, S. D. (1999). Pie-expansion efforts: collaboration processes in buyer-supplier relationships. Journal of marketing Research, 36(4), 461-475. https://doi.org/10.2307/3152000
- Jap, S. D., & Anderson, E. (2003). Safeguarding interorganizational performance and continuity under ex post opportunism. Management science, 49(12), 1684-1701. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.49.12.1684.25112
- Jeon, J. H. (2018). Foreign Uncertainty and Housing Distribution Market in Korea. Journal of Distribution Science, 16(12), 5-11. https://doi.org/10.15722/jds.16.12.201812.5
- Judge, W. (2010). Corporate governance mechanisms throughout the world. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 18(3), 159-160. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2010.00800.x
- Khan, H. (2011). A literature review of corporate governance. In International Conference on E-business, Management and Economics, 25, 1-5.
- Klein, S., Frazier, G. L., & Roth, V. J. (1990). A transaction cost analysis model of channel integration in international markets. Journal of Marketing research, 27, 196-208. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224379002700207
- Kotler, P., & Armstrong, G. (2010). Principles of marketing. Pearson education.
- Luo, Y. (2007). Are joint venture partners more opportunistic in a more volatile environment?. Strategic Management Journal, 28(1), 39-60. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.564
- Lusch, R. F., & Brown, J. R. (1996). Interdependency, contracting, and relational behavior in marketing channels. The journal of Marketing, 60(4), 19-38. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224299606000404
- Moorman, C., Zaltman, G., & Deshpande, R. (1992). Relationships between providers and users of market research: The dynamics of trust. Journal of marketing research, 29(3), 314-328. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224379202900303
- Medlin, C., & Quester, P. (2002, December). Inter-firm trust: Two theoretical dimensions versus a global measure. In Proceedings of the 18th annual IMP conference, Autumn 2002, Perth, Australia.
- Noordewier, T. G., John, G., & Nevin, J. R. (1990). Performance outcomes of purchasing arrangements in industrial buyer-vendor relationships. the Journal of Marketing, 54(4), 80-93. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224299005400407
- Ouchi, W. G. (1979). A conceptual framework for the design of organizational control mechanisms. In Readings in accounting for management control (pp. 63-82). Boston, MA.: Springer.
- Palmatier, R. W., Dant, R. P., & Grewal, D. (2007). A comparative longitudinal analysis of theoretical perspectives of interorganizational relationship performance. Journal of marketing, 71(4), 172-194. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkg.71.4.172
- Pavlou, P. A., Liang, H., & Xue, Y. (2007). Understanding and mitigating uncertainty in online exchange relationships: A principal-agent perspective. MIS quarterly, 31(1), 105-136. https://doi.org/10.2307/25148783
- Roh, B. G., Kim, H. S., Yoo, C. G., & Kim, G.P. (2015). Counteractions against Changes of Logistics Environment in Northeast Asia. Journal of distribution science, 13(5), 23-31. https://doi.org/10.15722/JDS.13.5.201505.23
- Santoro, M. D., & McGill, J. P. (2005). The effect of uncertainty and asset co‐specialization on governance in biotechnology alliances. Strategic Management Journal, 26(13), 1261-1269. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.506
- Schurr, P. H., & Ozanne, J. L. (1985). Influences on exchange processes: Buyers' preconceptions of a seller's trustworthiness and bargaining toughness. Journal of consumer research, 11(4), 939-953. https://doi.org/10.1086/209028
- Sengun, A. E. (2010). Which type of trust for inter-firm learning?. Industry and Innovation, 17(2), 193-213. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662711003633447
- Stump, R. L., & Heide, J. B. (1996). Controlling supplier opportunism in industrial relationships. Journal of Marketing Research, 33(4), 431-441. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224379603300405
- Trevino, L. J., & Kerr, J. L. (2015). Strategic and Organizational Responses of Mexican Managers to Environmental Uncertainty. In Proceedings of the 1997 World Marketing Congress (pp.360-363). Springer, Cham.
- Weitz, B. A., & Jap, S. D. (1995). Relationship marketing and distribution channels. Journal of the academy of Marketing Science, 23(4), 305-320. https://doi.org/10.1177/009207039502300411
- Williamson, O. (1985). The institutions of capitalism. New York: The Free Press.
- Wuyts, S., & Van den Bulte, C. (2012). Network governance. In Lilien, G. L., Handbook on Business to Business Marketing(pp.73-89), Northhampton
- Yoon, N.S. & Kim, Y. I. (2014). The distribution industry's social responsibility and ethics management: effects on corporate trust and loyalty. Journal of distribution science, 12(7), 23-35. https://doi.org/10.13106/jds.2014.vol12.no7.23.
- Young, G., Sapienza, H., & Baumer, D. (2003). The influence of flexibility in buyer-seller relationships on the productivity of knowledge. Journal of Business Research, 56(6), 443-451. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0148-2963(01)00243-0
- Zaheer, A., McEvily, B., & Perrone, V. (1998). Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and interpersonal trust on performance. Organization science, 9(2), 141-159. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.9.2.141
- Zand, D. E. (1972). Trust and managerial problem solving. Administrative science quarterly, 76(6), 229-239. https://doi.org/10.2307/2393957
Cited by
- A Research on the Relationship between Accrual-based Earnings Management and Real Earnings Management in the Retail Industry vol.17, pp.12, 2019, https://doi.org/10.15722/jds.17.12.201912.5
- An Analysis on the Competitiveness of the Oil Refinery Market in South Korea vol.7, pp.6, 2019, https://doi.org/10.13106/jafeb.2020.vol7.no6.145